Nearly every Eastern European nation faces a severe currency crisis. Indeed, no less an authority on the matter than Paul Krugman noted last October that the situation was "the mother of all currency crises." But what does this mean, how does it happen, and what needs to be done to done to stabilize the situation?
Let's consider a hypothetical country, Leveragestan. Let's say Leveragestan is a small country transitioning to a free market economy. They have a history of hyperinflation. They decide to peg their currency to a more stable currency (say the euro) to create a more credible investment environment. International capital pours in. The economy takes off. So far, so good. But the story so far is more complicated than simply "foreign money comes in and the economy grows." The international capital needs to be converted to the local currency (let's call them rubles). In terms of supply and demand, this creates more demand for rubles. To keep the ruble from gaining value (since they pegged it against the euro), the Leveragestan government must sell rubles on the foreign exchange markets, building up a reserve of foreign currency in return. Meanwhile, the new rubles in circulation within Leveragestan create a credit boom. Some of this money will go to legitimate investments. Some to speculation. And some to consumption. Soon Leveragestan increases its imports, and begins running a current accounts deficit. As long as the money keeps coming in from abroad, this isn't a problem. But what if international investors run for the exits?
First, why would foreign money suddenly stop coming in? Maybe Leveragestan's economy stops growing as fast as it was previously, and isn't as attractive an investment option anymore. Maybe the credit boom from the international capital created a speculative bubble that popped. Or maybe a major investment bank abroad collapsed, and investors everywhere are selling assets to raise cash. Regardless of the cause, once there is serious capital flight out of the country, Leveragestan's currency comes under assault. Its current accounts deficit, if large enough relative to the size of the economy, means that there is less demand for the Leveragestan ruble. The ruble is now overvalued. Subsequently, speculators begin to bet that it will decline. Leveragestan can defend its currency by using its foreign currency reserves to buy rubles on foreign exchange markets. But is more difficult to prop up a currency's value than to keep it down. Leveragestan can always print more rubles to put on foreign exchange markets if the government wants to keep the ruble from rising. They have a limited supply of foreign currency, however, to sell in order to keep the ruble from falling.
Once its foreign reserves dwindle, Leveragestan has two choices: raise interest rates or devalue the currency. Raising interest rates reduces the money supply and makes holding assets in Leveragestan more attractive; investments pay a higher rate of return. This could stop the capital flight. But spiking interest rates also choke off economic growth. Businesses can't borrow cheaply and hiring slows. A recession will follow. Devaluing carries its own risks. If done transparently and correctly, it will end the speculative attacks. Additionally, it will make Leveragestan's exports more competitive, since their goods will be cheaper abroad, and set the economy up for continued growth. Devaluing also gives investors confidence that assets are fairly priced. The perils are twofold: first, if done haphazardly, investors might panic, and the currency will fall more than it "should"; and second, that the real burden of debts denominated in foreign currencies will skyrocket for domestic borrowers.
Now where does Eastern Europe fit into this story? In the two decades since emerging from communism, the Eastern European countries have liberalized their economies, opening them to foreign investment, and pegging many of their currencies against the euro, in anticipation of someday joining the Eurozone. Western European banks - particularly Austrian, Swedish, and Belgian ones - lent heavily to Eastern Europe. This sparked a rise in consumption, and some gargantuan current account deficits. But the credit crisis has reversed this onetime frothy growth - and then some. As capital has left the region, Eastern European currencies have plummeted. While this would normally help their export sector, the reality is that with worldwide demand shriveling, there is no one to export to. Like Latvia, countries across Eastern Europe are contracting at or near double digit annual rates, as demand for their goods in Western Europe has disappeared.
This precipitous fall in GDP in conjunction with plunging currencies has created potentially a new source of contagion in world financial markets. First, let's consider the currencies. Raising interest rates to stem capital flight is not an option. Investors want to hold cash or safe government debt. This liquidity preference is, of course, not unique to Eastern Europe. But it means that offering higher rates of return will not dissuade investors from pulling their money out. And given the enormous current accounts deficits many Eastern European nations were running, this means - oftentimes massive - devaluation is the only option. Indeed, currencies across the region have fallen by nearly 20-50% against currencies such as the Swiss franc. This fall against the Swiss franc is particularly ominous, since so many Eastern European businesses and households took out loans and mortgages in Swiss francs during the bubble years to take advantage of low interest rates. But one example: 60% of Polish mortgages are denominated in Swiss francs; the Polish zloty has halved against the Swiss franc in recent weeks. As the real burden of debts of businesses and households nearly doubles across the region, defaults will skyrocket. Eastern Europe's cratering economies compound this problem. As job losses accelerate, even more borrowers will not be able to repay their debts - and that's before accounting for the rising real burden of debts as local currencies fall. This is Europe's subprime debacle. And its explosion will beget a new round of writedowns for Western European banks.
The web of financial interconnectedness is tangled and difficult to predict. But the failure of Western European banks - and countries - could potentially bring credit markets back to their apocalyptic post-Lehman levels. Austrian banks are perhaps most exposed to Eastern European debt, but they themselves borrowed heavily from Swiss banks. Switzerland could find itself at risk of sovereign default if it needs to nationalize its banks, as bank liabilities are roughly 1050% of Swiss GDP (Iceland's bank liabilities comprised 1000% of GDP for comparison's sake). For many of the small Western European countries, their banks are both too big to fail and too big to save. Italian, Belgian, and Swedish banks are all also highly exposed. Only an EU-wide response can stave off complete disaster. This essentially means getting France and Germany to agree to bail out their neighbors. After denying reality for months - resisting calls for stimulus spending and bailing out at-risk European countries - the German Finance Minister made some noise recently about bailing out Ireland. This is a good start. But much more is needed.
This is where President Obama comes in. A collapse in the European banking sector would surely bring down American banks as well. While major American banks are more or less insolvent already, we have them on life support now. A disorderly bankruptcy in the markets would send them on a new and rapid death spiral. At the upcoming G20 summit, President Obama should push for increasing IMF funding, and giving it a greater mandate to bail out countries. He should also push the EU members to more aggressively cut rates and spend on fiscal stimulus. But most importantly, we need an internationally coordinated banking rescue plan. This is a tall order. Getting consensus within America on fixing the financial sector is difficult enough without bringing in foreign leaders as well. But our financial markets are so interconnected that coordination is more or less necessary.
In 1931, the Austrian bank Creditanstalt failed, setting off a new stage of bank runs across the world. Let us hope that history indeed does not repeat itself. And that we can learn from it.
Update: European leaders' unwillingness over the weekend to create a comprehensive Eastern Europe bailout fund a la Hungary's suggestion is not encouraging. Treating each country on a "case-by-case" basis echoes of American policy towards investment banks until October. Eventually, political leaders will likely get bailout fatigue, or policymakers will simply underestimate the systemic importance of a country/bank, and let the wrong one go. If moralizing sentiment like from this recent interview - Eastern Europeans must devalue despite the enormous real burden of debt this will create to "learn not to borrow in foreign currencies" - takes hold, then enough of Eastern Europe might go bust to start a new stage of financial panic.
No comments:
Post a Comment